+1 (315) 557-6473 

4 Common Questions to Help You Revise and Prepare for Your Online Tax and Spending Exams

We have prepared the questions and answers related to tax and spending below to help you revise for your exams. If there are any concepts in the topic you did not understand during class or need to polish on, then this blog is for you. The questions we have included cover the commonly tested subtopics in this unit. The blog focuses on the concept of crowding out in the IS-LM and AS-AD models and how we can test for it using macro-econometric models.

Discuss the concept of crowding out

Crowding out can be said to occur when an increase in government expenditure of say, £100m leads to an increase in national income of less than £100m. In this case, where total private expenditure falls, crowding out is associated with the existence of a multiplier effect of less than unity. Super-crowding out arises when the multiplier is negative.
Within the Keynesian paradigm, an increase in government expenditure would increase the level of national income by some multiple of the initial expenditure, through the multiplier process. Some resources would thus be acquired by the public sector, but the resulting income of the private sector would be greater than it was before: so fiscal expansion is a free lunch. Of course, even in this favorable case, some private sector expenditures (notably investment) could fall (partial crowding out). This picture may be correct in a deep depression, but it would not seem to characterize the behavior of modern economies closer to the full employment level of output; although it is important to realize that an antipathetic attitude to state intervention is not new. Rather, it is as old as economics itself.
The Keynesian view is the misfit, though this does not make it wrong. Spencer and Yohe (1970), for example, point out that even Adam Smith believed that government spending financed by borrowing involved 'the destruction of some capital which had before existed in the country, by the perversion of some portion of the annual produce which had before been destined for the maintenance of productive labour, towards that of unproductive labour' (Wealth of Nations, 1937 edn, p. 878). Spencer and Yohe (1970, p. 15) also refer to Hawtrey’s evidence to the Macmillan Committee in 1930: 'Hawtrey’s stated that whether the spending came out of taxes or loans from savings, the increased governmental expenditures would merely replace private expenditures.'
The resurgence of a belief in crowding out was associated with the Monetarist critique, but it did not flow directly from the work of Friedman himself. Rather, the main impetus came from the work of Anderson and Jordan (1968). They ran a reduced-form regression of money national income on current and lagged values of government expenditure and current and lagged values of the money stock. The results indicated that while the impact effect of expenditure was positive this was soon offset by negative effects, so that, 'A change in Federal spending financed by either borrowing or taxes has only a negligible effect on GNP over a period of about a year' (Carlson and Spencer, 1975, p. 3). Monetary expansion, on the other hand, had a positive cumulative effect. For more recent estimates of the 'St Louis equation' see Batten and Hafer (1983).
The Anderson and Jordan result has been widely discredited. This is partly due to the failure of their equation on more recent data. More important is the theoretical argument of Goldfeld and Blinder (1972) who point to the inaccuracy of reduced-form techniques when the government reacts systematically to the state of the economy. An intuitive explanation of the Goldfeld-Blinder point is presented by Chrystal and Alt (1979). If fiscal stabilization policy is designed to offset the effects of fluctuations in an exogenous variable, there need be no correlation between income and the budget deficit even if fiscal policy is working perfectly as a stabilizer.
A further important point to be aware of before proceeding is that the crowding-out issue is often regarded as being identical to the question of the effects of the government budget constraint. The latter arises because if the government runs a budget deficit, this must be financed by printing money, borrowing, or raising taxes. This restriction has often been ignored in the past; indeed it is in all three textbook models above. We shall see below that crowding out could occur even without a government budget constraint but that, once the government's financing requirement is taken into account, crowding out becomes so much more likely as to be highly probable, except when there is considerable slack in the economy.

With the help of a graph, explain how crowding out affects the classical IS-LM model. Show the shifts in the LM and IS curves as government expenditure and interest rates change.

One common interpretation of both the Monetarist and the Classical case arises if the demand for money is strictly proportional to income. The effect of this in terms of Model II is that the LM curve becomes vertical. This is illustrated in Figure 10.1 where LM, is the relevant curve. A shift of the IS curve from IS1, to IS2, caused by an increase in government expenditure in Model I (the Keynesian expenditure system) would have caused an increase in income from Y0 to Y1, but with a vertical LM curve there can be no increase in income. Rather, the interest rate rises to r, until there has been a reduction in private investment equal to the initial rise in government expenditure.
Crowding out in the Classical IS LM model

Fig 10.1 Crowding out in the Classical IS-LM model.

Crowding out of private investment, say, on LM1 at an interest rate of r1 However, the rise in income from Y0 to Y1 could represent a multiplier in excess of unity.

Illustrate how an increase in government expenditure moves the economy in the classical AD-AS model

It should be clear that if we add a supply side to the model, crowding out will be even more likely to occur. This is pictured in Figure 10.2. The short-run aggregate supply curve AS, is upward sloping because labour supply depends upon expected prices, whereas demand for labour depends upon actual prices. There is a rise in output in the short run because expectations lag behind actuality and so there is a temporary fall in the real wage. More labour is employed and more output produced.

An initial increase in government expenditure would move the economy.

Crowding out in the Classical AD AS model

Figure 10.2 Crowding out in the Classical AD-AS model.

from A to B (ignoring the government budget constraint). However, over time price expectations will catch up with reality and, as they does, the short-run aggregate supply curve will shift up to the left. Eventually the economy will settle again at C where output is on the long-run aggregate supply curve. The increase in government expenditure will have crowded out private expenditures of an equal amount. It will be largely private investment that is crowded out, since the fall in the real money stock will raise interest rates Thus the story we are left with from this model is that crowding out is quite likely in the long run but there may be a short period during which government expenditure leads to income increases through the multiplier process. Only if the economy could be shown to start off well to the left of the 4S, curve, and not to be there because of an inflation cycle, could we argue that there was a chance that there would be no long-run crowding out.

An additional factor which could increase the likelihood of short-run crowding out would be if price expectations are formed 'rationally', in the sense defined in Chapter 4. It has implicitly been assumed above that price expectations are formed adaptively, as a revision from the prediction error made last time. If, however, all actors understand the model and realize that the expansion of government expenditure is going to raise prices, it could be that there will be no short-run output gain at all. Rather, the AS, curve will shift up rapidly and the economy will go straight from A to C. This is the source of the argument that only unanticipated policy changes will have any real effects.

The remaining question concerns the position of the long-run supply curve. It has been argued that this will be positioned at the level of output corresponding to the NAIRU-the natural rate of output. This is basically determined from year to year by the underlying growth trend of the economy. It would seem from the above analysis that the only chance of long-run crowding out not occurring is if rises in government expenditure can increase the underlying growth potential of the economy. This is certainly possible; we examine this question in more detail at the end of this chapter. Nevertheless, the most vociferous commentators on this issue believe that exactly the opposite will occur. Brunner and Meltzer (1976, p. 769), for example, argue that:

Reduction in the output of the private sector could, in principle, be offset by the increased output of the public sector, it does not happen. Instead, there are loans or subsidies to enterprises that earn no profit or suffer large losses. Private saving is directed, in this case, toward enterprises that often do not earn rates of return equal to the interest on the bonds issued to finance the government budget deficit. Or, investment is used to increase 'prestige' as in the case of Concorde, national airlines, steamship lines and other enterprises that operate at negative rates of return. These enterprises direct material, skilled labour, and capital toward less productive uses than the private output that is crowded out. The list of such enterprises can be Absorption of labour by the government does not substitute public out expanded by every knowledgeable reader.

Absorption of labour by the government does not substitute public output for private output of equivalent value. Much public employment has the opposite effect. Complex rules and regulations absorb the time of civil servants and create demands in the private sector for lawyers, accountants, negotiators and clerks to keep abreast of the rules, to fill out the forms and hopefully to obtain more favourable interpretations than competitors have obtained.

Explain ways in which we can test for the presence of crowding out

One way of testing for the presence of crowding out is to use estimated econometric forecasting models to simulate the effects of various policy changes. The Macroeconomic Modeling Bureau based at Warwick University regularly undertakes comparative simulations of the major UK models. Church and Whitley (1991) present the results of simulations on the Treasury and Bank of England (and other) models (as of June 1991). As a cautionary preamble, it is worth recalling the criticisms of this procedure made by Robert Lucas (see Chapter 4 in this book). Such exercises require the structural model of the economy to be policy invariant. There is no reason to believe that this is so. As a result, the safest conclusion is that these simulations tell us a lot about the properties of the model in question but, perhaps, not very much about the properties of the economy itself.

Table 10.1 reports the effects produced in the Treasury and Bank of England models of a rise in government spending under two different assumptions. The first simulation is for a rise of government consumption of £2bn, holding interest rates fixed, while the second fixes the exchange rate. The simulations allow the full range of supply and demand effects to work through. The long-run multiplier implied by the models for both taxes and government spending is about one, although the effects on other variables like inflation and the balance of payments differ between the two cases; for example, a cut in income tax tends to reduce pressure on wages so inflation is lower than when government spending rises. The effect on the balance of trade is the reverse, but as the table shows, the results are very sensitive to the assumption about the exchange rate. If the exchange rate is fixed, then the consequences of a rise in government spending are quite different; output falls, and the multiplier is negative. If nothing else, this

Table 10.1 Percentage effect on real GDP of a £2 billion rise in government spending (1990 prices) and equivalent fall in income tax.


Year
Bank
HMT

1

3

5

1

3

5

G (i)

0.40

0.53

0.56

0.43

0.50

0.46

G (ii)

0.36

-0.20

-1.10

0.39

0.15

-0.36

T (i)

0.13

0.40

0.59

0.11

0.34

0.52

Notes: (i) fixed interest rate; (1) fixed exchange rate.

example serves as a salutary lesson about the relationship between simple economic theory and actual economies. In theory, a boost to government spending raises interest rates which leads to upward pressure on the pound; the government is forced to respond by expanding the money supply and reducing interest rates, thus expanding the economy. In the 'real' model, the worsening current account leads to a potential depreciation, forcing higher interest rates in defense of the exchange rate, reducing aggregate demand.


Comments
No comments yet be the first one to post a comment!
Post a comment